翻訳と辞書
Words near each other
・ Reta Jo Lewis
・ Reta Shaw
・ Reta Trotman
・ Reta Vortaro
・ Retable
・ Retablo
・ Retagliado bianco
・ Retail
・ Retail (comic strip)
・ Retail advertising
・ Retail Bakers of America
・ Retail banking
・ Retail Banking Academy
・ Retail clerk
・ Retail Clerks International Union
Retail concentration
・ Retail Council of Canada
・ Retail design
・ Retail Employees Superannuation Trust
・ Retail floorplan
・ Retail Food Group
・ Retail foreign exchange trading
・ Retail geography
・ Retail in the Republic of Ireland
・ Retail Industry Leaders Association
・ Retail Intelligence
・ Retail Investor Protection Act
・ Retail Leasing
・ Retail loss prevention
・ Retail media


Dictionary Lists
翻訳と辞書 辞書検索 [ 開発暫定版 ]
スポンサード リンク

Retail concentration : ウィキペディア英語版
Retail concentration
Retail concentration refers to the market-share generally belonging to the top 4 or 5 mass distribution firms present in a regional market, as a percentage of the total.
Retail concentration is not simply a concentration ratio as is emerging in the food sector. This is due to two factors: the particular relevance retail is gaining on a global scale, and the particular shape of the food supply chain.
In recent years, Retail Concentration moved ahead with fusions and acquisitions〔http://www.capgemini.com/resources/news/consumers_drive_food_industry_transformation__global_brands_retail_formats_consolidation__says_new_report/〕 along the entire food supply chain. We can assume with Grievink (2003) that in a few years there will be only 5 dominant actors in the globalised food chain.〔http://www.foodinternational.net/articles/efi-special/1249/state-of-the-art-in-food.html〕
The same researcher states that in the 90's the top-5 food manufacturers could count on twice the cash flow of the top-5 retailers. Nowadays the relation is inverted: the top 5 retailers can count on twice that of the top-5 manufacturers.
Thus, the food chain has become increasingly vertically integrated, with global corporations able to coordinate inputs from the seed to the field, from the stable to the table. Retail concentration by one hand is the answer that retail is giving to compete with the giants of agrofood industry. By the other hand, is the agrofood industry in itself searching to arrive directly to the consumers, through a refined relations system. In this process, private labels are increasingly attracting consumers, and are expected to grow more and more on their fidelisation strategy, beating on quality, safety and also ethical values.〔http://www.foodinternational.net/articles/efi-special/583/private-labels-why-europe-is-leading-the-pack.html 〕
Recently the European Commission〔http://ec.europa.eu/economy_finance/thematic_articles/article13524_en.htm 〕 proposed solutions to face with overall price increase about foodstuff. Among the measures proposed, several relate to the retail power recently acquired.
In particular, the payments delay to the producers; the additional fees asked to the producers to place on the shelves branded products; price transparency; better regulation on promotional activities and openings/closing time are all issues on the agenda.
For supporters, retail concentration means more chances for consumers, lower prices, better quality. For opponents, by the contrary, the disappearing of traditional shops, of food culture, of neighborhood life in general.〔International Journal of Behavioral Nutrition and Physical Activity, 2006 3: 33 “Understanding environmental influences on nutrition and physical activity behaviors: where should we look and what should we count?”, Kylie Ball, Anna F Timperio and David A Crawford〕 Furthermore, too much concentration means squeezing the price of industry and of agriculture, which can lead to outsourcing food from anywhere it can cost less, without a truly long term impact assessment.
Tim Lang (Food Wars, Earthscan London 2004) described the retail concentration phenomenon such as a "food war", in which winners and losers take place. Tim Lang talks about "food clusters" (()) to better handle the idea of concentration along the entire food chain.
There are a lot of legal instruments which allow to get more and more concentrated.
Acquisition being the first one, follow mergers, joint ventures, partnerships and more not formalised contracts/ agreements.
Note that the "hypermarketization" is not limited to the Western World, but supermarkets rise fast also in the less developed countries and in the East and in the South of the World.
.
Regarding that, there are a lot of concerns, pretending that the overwhelming power of retailing is making poorer and poorer farmers, in particular in the LDC (Less Developed Countries).〔http://www.agobservatory.org/library.cfm?RefID=46604 〕 The "crowding out" effect on local agricultures it is basically due to the global sourcing of the produces, wherever they cost less and offer more. To say it with the words of the Italian food-thinker Corrado Finardi to fairly function, the agricultural system has a different, slower timeline than the market (in agriculture counts the long term investment, while on the global market it is more important the precise moment in which supply and demand match).
Market concentration (considering the upper and lower tails)
A more refined form, which calculates the percentage of last 4/ competitors on the first 4/5.
Eve in its static version, it measures the level of competition in the sector.
A diachronic comparison allows for even more insights.

Herfindahl Hirschman Index
This index is used in Europe and in the USA for antitrust regulatory purposes, in order to assess the feasibility of mergers and acquisitions.
The HHI is calculated as the relative frequencies squared and summed, comprehensive of all actors in the playfield. So far, it gives more importance to biggest player in proportion.
Even if interesting, a HHI, often wrongly assess the real behaviours on the field.
Consider, for the comparison sake, the retail concentration in Europe. Top 5 retail distributors account for the 70% of the market share. Even if apparently it gives the idea of a highly concentrated market, the HHI does not allow for that conclusion in most of the cases.
Following 3 different scenarios, we explored the relative market shares of the single actors.
1 scenario: 1= 19%, 2=15%, 3=14%, 4= 12%, 5=10% (total=70% for the top 5), remaining= 2%, 3%, 4%, 5%, 7%, 9%.
In this first case, where there is a linear distribution of market share among players, the HHI scores at 0,121 (considered a moderate concentration indicator)
2 scenario: 14%
*5 (top 5 players =70%, having equal market share), the remaining, each equalling 3% (3%
*10). In this second case, the HHI scores an 0,098, which stands for an unconcentrated market at all. We can deliberately make some reflections on that, since the HHI seems not taking into account opportunistic behaviours in the direction of oligopoly. It is assumed that, because of the equal market power of the top 5 actors, they are going to compete (even if history shows that more probably they find some form of implicit agreement…). Standardised from 0 to 1, the value is 0,033571429 (very low…).
3 scenario. First player= 20%, followers 12%, then 10%, 9%, 8%, 7%, 4% and the last 10 each 3%.
In this case the HHI is 0,0944 (not concentrated market, even if not highly competitive environment). Standardised from 0 to 1, the value is 0,0378 (very low…).
Even in a case where there is one leading competitor which “makes the market” as in the 3rd scenario, the HHI stays relatively low.
== References ==


抄文引用元・出典: フリー百科事典『 ウィキペディア(Wikipedia)
ウィキペディアで「Retail concentration」の詳細全文を読む



スポンサード リンク
翻訳と辞書 : 翻訳のためのインターネットリソース

Copyright(C) kotoba.ne.jp 1997-2016. All Rights Reserved.